投资学10版习题答案11

CHAPTER 11: THE EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS

PROBLEM SETS

1. The correlation coefficient between stock returns for two nonoverlapping periods

should be zero. If not, returns from one period could be used to predict returns in later periods and make abnormal profits.

2. No. Microsoft’s continuing profitability does not imply that stock market investors

who purchased Microsoft shares after its success was already evident would have earned an exceptionally high return on their investments. It simply means that

Microsoft has made risky investments over the years that have paid off in the form of increased cash flows and profitability. Microsoft shareholders have benefited from the risk-expected return tradeoff, which is consistent with the EMH.

3. Expected rates of return differ because of differential risk premiums across all

securities.

4. No. The value of dividend predictability would be already reflected in the

stock price.

5. No, markets can be efficient even if some investors earn returns above the market

average. Consider the Lucky Event issue: Ignoring transaction costs, about 50% of professional investors, by definition, will “beat” the market in any given year. The probability of beating it three years in a row, though small, is not insignificant.

Beating the market in the past does not predict future success as three years of

returns make up too small a sample on which to base correlation let alone causation.

6. Volatile stock prices could reflect volatile underlying economic conditions as large

amounts of information being incorporated into the price will cause variability in stock price. The efficient market hypothesis suggests that investors cannot earn

excess risk-adjusted rewards. The variability of the stock price is thus reflected in the expected returns as returns and risk are positively correlated.

7. The following effects seem to suggest predictability within equity markets and thus

disprove the efficient market hypothesis. However, consider the following:

a. Multiple studies suggest that “value” stocks (measured often by low P/E

multiples) earn higher returns over time than “growth” stocks (high P/E multiples). This could suggest a strategy for earning higher returns over time. However, another rational argument may be that traditional forms of CAPM (such as Sharpe’s model) do not fully account for all risk factors that affect a firm’s price level. A firm viewed as riskier may have a lower price and thus P/E multiple.

b. The book-to-market effect suggests that an investor can earn excess returns by investing in companies with high book value (the value of a firm’s assets minus its liabilities divided by the number of shares outstanding) to market value. A study by Fama and French1 suggests that book-to-market value reflects a risk factor that is not accounted for by traditional one variable CAPM. For example, companies

experiencing financial distress see the ratio of book to market value increase. Thus a more complex CAPM that includes book-to-market value as an explanatory variable should be used to test market anomalies.

c. Stock price momentum can be positively correlated with past performance (short to intermediate horizon) or negatively correlated (long horizon). Historical data

seem to imply statistical significance to these patterns. Explanations for this include a bandwagon effect or the behaviorists’ (see Chapter 12) explanation that there is a tendency for investors to underreact to new information, thus producing a positive serial correlation. However, statistical significance does not imply economic

significance. Several studies that included transaction costs in the momentum

models discovered that momentum traders tended to not outperform the efficient market hypothesis strategy of buy and hold.

d. The small-firm effect states that smaller firms produce better returns than larger firms. Since 1926, returns from small firms outpace large firm stock returns by

about 1% per year. Do small cap investors earn excess risk-adjusted returns?

The measure of systematic risk according to Sharpe’s CAPM is the stock’s beta (or sensitivity of returns of the stock to market returns). If the stock’s beta is the best explanation of risk, then the small-firm effect does indicate an inefficient market. Dividing the market into deciles based on their betas shows an increasing

relationship between betas and returns. Fama and French2 show that the empirical relationship between beta and stock returns is flat over a fairly long horizon (1963–1990). Breaking the market into deciles based on sizes and then examining the

relationship between beta and stock returns within each size decile exhibits this flat relationship. This implies that firm size may be a better measure of risk than beta and the size-effect should not be viewed as an indicator that markets are inefficient. Heuristically this makes sense, as smaller firms are generally viewed as risky

compared to larger firms and perceived risk and return are positively correlated. 1 Fama, Eugene and Kenneth French, “Common Risk Factors in the Returns on Stocks and Bonds,” Journal of Finance 33:1, pp. 3-56.

2 Ibid

In addition this effect seems to be endpoint and data sensitive. For example, smaller

stocks did not outperform larger stocks from the mid-1980s through the 1990s. In addition, databases contain stock returns from companies that have survived and do not include returns of those that went bankrupt. Thus small-firm data may exhibit survivorship bias.

Over the long haul, there is an expected upward drift in stock prices based on their fair expected rates of return. The fair expected return over any single day is very small (e.g., 12% per year is only about 0.03% per day), so that on any day the price is virtually equally likely to rise or fall. Over longer periods, the small expected

daily returns accumulate, and upward moves are more likely than downward ones. Remember that economies tend to grow over time and stock prices tend to follow economic growth, so it is only natural that there is an upward drift in equity prices. c. This is a predictable pattern in returns that should not occur if the weak-form

EMH is valid.

Acute market inefficiencies are temporary in nature and are more easily

exploited than chronic inefficiencies. A temporary drop in a stock price due to

a large sale would be more easily exploited than the chronic inefficiencies

mentioned in the other responses.

This is a classic filter rule that should not produce superior returns in an

efficient market.

This is the definition of an efficient market.

Though stock prices follow a random walk and intraday price changes do

appear to be a random walk, over the long run there is compensation for

bearing market risk and for the time value of money. Investing differs from a

casino in that in the long-run, an investor is compensated for these risks, while

a player at a casino faces less than fair-game odds.

In an efficient market, any predictable future prospects of a company have

already been priced into the current value of the stock. Thus, a stock share

price can still follow a random walk.

While the random nature of dart board selection seems to follow naturally

from efficient markets, the role of rational portfolio management still exists. It 8. 9. 10. a. 11. c. 12. b. 13. a. b. c.

exists to ensure a well-diversified portfolio, to assess the risk-tolerance of the

investor, and to take into account tax code issues.

14. d. In a semistrong-form efficient market, it is not possible to earn abnormally

high profits by trading on publicly available information. Information about

P/E ratios and recent price changes is publicly known. On the other hand, an

investor who has advance knowledge of management improvements could

earn abnormally high trading profits (unless the market is also strong-form

efficient).

15. Market efficiency implies investors cannot earn excess risk-adjusted profits. If the

stock price run-up occurs when only insiders know of the coming dividend increase, then it is a violation of strong-form efficiency. If the public also knows of the

increase, then this violates semistrong-form efficiency.

16. While positive beta stocks respond well to favorable new information about the

economy’s progress through the business cycle, they should not show abnormal

returns around already anticipated events. If a recovery, for example, is already

anticipated, the actual recovery is not news. The stock price should already reflect the coming recovery.

17. a. Consistent. Based on pure luck, half of all managers should beat the market

in any year.

b. Inconsistent. This would be the basis of an “easy money” rule: simply invest

with last year's best managers.

c. Consistent. In contrast to predictable returns, predictable volatility does not

convey a means to earn abnormal returns.

d. Inconsistent. The abnormal performance ought to occur in January when

earnings are announced.

e. Inconsistent. Reversals offer a means to earn easy money: just buy last

week’s losers.

18. The return on the market is 8%. Therefore, the forecast monthly return for Ford is:

0.10% + (1.1 × 8%) = 8.9%

Ford ’s actual return was 7%, so the abnormal return was –1.9%.

19. a. Based on broad market trends, the CAPM indicates that AmbChaser stock

should have increased by: 1.0% + 2.0 × (1.5% – 1.0%) = 2.0%

Its firm-specific (nonsystematic) return due to the lawsuit is $1 million per

$100 million initial equity, or 1%. Therefore, the total return should be 3%. (It

is assumed here that the outcome of the lawsuit had a zero expected value.)

If the settlement was expected to be $2 million, then the actual settlement was

a “$1 million disappointment,” and so the firm-specific return would be –1%,

for a total return of 2% – 1% = 1%. b.

20. Given market performance, predicted returns on the two stocks would be:

Apex:

Bpex: 0.2% + (1.4 × 3%) = 4.4% –0.1% + (0.6 × 3%) = 1.7%

Apex underperformed this prediction; Bpex outperformed the prediction. We

conclude that Bpex won the lawsuit.

21. a. E (r M ) = 12%, r f = 4% and β = 0.5

Therefore, the expected rate of return is:

4% + 0.5 × (12% – 4%) = 8%

If the stock is fairly priced, then E (r ) = 8%.

b. If r M falls short of your expectation by 2% (that is, 10% – 12%) then you

would expect the return for Changing Fortunes Industries to fall short of your

original expectation by: β × 2% = 1%

Therefore, you would forecast a revised expectation for Changing Fortunes of:

8% – 1% = 7%

Given a market return of 10%, you would forecast a return for Changing

Fortunes of 7%. The actual return is 10%. Therefore, the surprise due to firm-

specific factors is 10% – 7% = 3%, which we attribute to the settlement.

Because the firm is initially worth $100 million, the surprise amount of the

settlement is 3% of $100 million, or $3 million, implying that the prior

expectation for the settlement was only $2 million. c.

22. Implicit in the dollar-cost averaging strategy is the notion that stock prices

fluctuate around a “normal” level. Otherwise, there is no meaning to statements

such as: “when the price is high.” How do we know, for example, whether a price of $25 today will turn out to be viewed as high or low compared to the stock price six months from now?

23. The market responds positively to new news. If the eventual recovery is anticipated,

then the recovery is already reflected in stock prices. Only a better-than-expected recovery should affect stock prices.

24. Buy. In your view, the firm is not as bad as everyone else believes it to be.

Therefore, you view the firm as undervalued by the market. You are less pessimistic about the firm’s prospects than the beliefs built into the stock price.

25. Here we need a two-factor model relating Ford’s return to those of both the broad

market and the auto industry. If we call r I the industry return, then we would first estimate parameters α,βM ,βIND in the following regression:

r FORD =α+βM r M +βIND r IND +ε

Given these estimates we would calculate Ford’s firm-specific return as:

26. The market may have anticipated even greater earnings. Compared to prior

expectations, the announcement was a disappointment.

27. Thinly traded stocks will not have a considerable amount of market research

performed on the companies they represent. This neglected-firm effect implies a greater degree of uncertainty with respect to smaller companies. Thus positive

CAPM alphas among thinly traded stocks do not necessarily violate the efficient market hypothesis since these higher alphas are actually risk premiums, not market inefficiencies.

28. The negative abnormal returns (downward drift in CAR) just prior to stock

purchases suggest that insiders deferred their purchases until after bad news was released to the public. This is evidence of valuable inside information. The positive abnormal returns after purchase suggest insider purchases in anticipation of good news. The analysis is symmetric for insider sales.

29. a. The market risk premium moves countercyclical to the economy, peaking in

recessions. A violation of the efficient market hypothesis would imply that investors could take advantage of this predictability and earn excess risk adjusted returns. However, several studies, including Siegel,3 show that successfully timing the 3 Jeremy Siegel, Stocks for the Long Run: The Definitive Guide to Financial Market Returns and Long-Term Investment Strategies, 2002, New York: McGraw-Hill.

r FORD -[α+βM r M +βIND r IND +ε] This estimate of firm-specific news would measure the market’s assessment of the potential profitability of Ford’s new model.

b. changes have eluded professional investors thus far. Moreover a changing risk premium implies changing required rates of return for stocks rather than an inefficiency with the market. As the market risk premium increases during a recession, stocks prices tend to fall.

As the economy recovers, the market risk premium falls, and stock prices tend to rise. These changes could give investors the impression that markets overreact,

especially if the underlying changes in the market risk premium are small but

cumulative. For example, the October Crash of 1987 is commonly viewed as an

example of market overreaction. However, in the weeks running up to mid-October, several underlying changes to the market risk premium occurred (in addition to

changes in the yields on long-term Treasury Bonds). Congress threatened investors with a “merger tax” that would have truncated the booming merger industry and loosened the discipline that the threat of mergers provides to a firm’s management. In addition, the Secretary of Treasury threatened further depreciation in the value of the dollar, frightening foreign investors. These events may have increased the

market risk premium and lowered stock prices in a seeming overreaction.

CFA PROBLEMS

1. b. Semistrong form efficiency implies that market prices reflect all publicly

available information concerning past trading history as well as fundamental

aspects of the firm.

2. a. The full price adjustment should occur just as the news about the dividend

becomes publicly available.

3. d. If low P/E stocks tend to have positive abnormal returns, this would represent

an unexploited profit opportunity that would provide evidence that investors

are not using all available information to make profitable investments.

4. c. In an efficient market, no securities are consistently overpriced or underpriced.

While some securities will turn out after any investment period to have

provided positive alphas (i.e., risk-adjusted abnormal returns) and some

negative alphas, these past returns are not predictive of future returns.

5. c. A random walk implies that stock price changes are unpredictable, using past

price changes or any other data.

6.

7.

8. d. A gradual adjustment to fundamental values would allow for the use of strategies based on past price movements in order to generate abnormal profits. a. a. Some empirical evidence that supports the EMH:

(i) Professional money managers do not typically earn higher returns than

comparable risk, passive index strategies.

(ii) Event studies typically show that stocks respond immediately to the

public release of relevant news.

(iii) Most tests of technical analysis find that it is difficult to identify price

trends that can be exploited to earn superior risk-adjusted investment

returns.

Some evidence that is difficult to reconcile with the EMH concerns simple

portfolio strategies that apparently would have provided high risk-adjusted

returns in the past. Some examples of portfolios with attractive historical returns: (i) Low P/E stocks.

(ii) High book-to-market ratio stocks.

(iii) Small firms in January.

(iv) Firms with very poor stock price performance in the last few months.

Other evidence concerns post-earnings-announcement stock price drift and

intermediate-term price momentum.

An investor might choose not to index even if markets are efficient because he

or she may want to tailor a portfolio to specific tax considerations or to specific risk management issues, for example, the need to hedge (or at least not add to)

exposure to a particular source of risk (e.g., industry exposure).

The efficient market hypothesis (EMH) states that a market is efficient if

security prices immediately and fully reflect all available relevant information.

If the market fully reflects information, the knowledge of that information

would not allow an investor to profit from the information because stock

prices already incorporate the information.

i. The weak form of the EMH asserts that stock prices reflect all the information that can be derived by examining market trading data such as the history of past prices and trading volume.

A strong body of evidence supports weak-form efficiency in the major U.S.

securities markets. For example, test results suggest that technical trading rules do not produce superior returns after adjusting for transaction costs and taxes. b. c. 9. a.

ii. The semistrong form states that a firm’s stock price reflects all publicly

available information about a firm’s prospects. Examples of publicly available

information are company annual reports and investment advisory data.

Evidence strongly supports the notion of semistrong efficiency, but occasional

studies (e.g., identifying market anomalies such as the small-firm-in-January or book-to-market effects) and events (e.g. stock market crash of October 19, 1987) are inconsistent with this form of market efficiency. There is a question

concerning the extent to which these “anomalies” result from data mining.

iii. The strong form of the EMH holds that current market prices reflect all

information (whether publicly available or privately held) that can be relevant

to the valuation of the firm.

Empirical evidence suggests that strong-form efficiency does not hold. If this

form were correct, prices would fully reflect all information. Therefore even

insiders could not earn excess returns. But the evidence is that corporate

officers do have access to pertinent information long enough before public

release to enable them to profit from trading on this information.

b. i. Technical analysis involves the search for recurrent and predictable patterns in

stock prices in order to enhance returns. The EMH implies that technical analysis is without value. If past prices contain no useful information for predicting future prices, there is no point in following any technical trading rule.

ii. Fundamental analysis uses earnings and dividend prospects of the firm,

expectations of future interest rates, and risk evaluation of the firm to determine proper stock prices. The EMH predicts that most fundamental analysis is doomed to failure. According to semistrong-form efficiency, no investor can earn excess returns from trading rules based on publicly available information. Only analysts with unique insight achieve superior returns.

In summary, the EMH holds that the market appears to adjust so quickly to

information about both individual stocks and the economy as a whole that no

technique of selecting a portfolio using either technical or fundamental analysis can consistently outperform a strategy of simply buying and holding a diversified

portfolio of securities, such as those comprising the popular market indexes.

c. Portfolio managers have several roles and responsibilities even in perfectly

efficient markets. The most important responsibility is to identify the risk/return objectives for a portfolio given the investor’s constraints. In an efficient market, portfolio managers are responsible for tailoring the portfolio to meet the investor’s needs, rather than to beat the market, which requires identifying the client’s return requirements and risk tolerance. Rational portfolio management also requires

examining the investor’s constraints, including liquidity, time horizon, laws and regulations, taxes, and unique preferences and circumstances such as age and

employment.

10. a. The earnings (and dividend) growth rate of growth stocks may be consistently

overestimated by investors. Investors may extrapolate recent growth too far into the future and thereby downplay the inevitable slowdown. At any given time,

growth stocks are likely to revert to (lower) mean returns and value stocks are

likely to revert to (higher) mean returns, often over an extended future time

horizon.

In efficient markets, the current prices of stocks already reflect all known relevant information. In this situation, growth stocks and value stocks provide the same

risk-adjusted expected return. b.

CHAPTER 11: THE EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS

PROBLEM SETS

1. The correlation coefficient between stock returns for two nonoverlapping periods

should be zero. If not, returns from one period could be used to predict returns in later periods and make abnormal profits.

2. No. Microsoft’s continuing profitability does not imply that stock market investors

who purchased Microsoft shares after its success was already evident would have earned an exceptionally high return on their investments. It simply means that

Microsoft has made risky investments over the years that have paid off in the form of increased cash flows and profitability. Microsoft shareholders have benefited from the risk-expected return tradeoff, which is consistent with the EMH.

3. Expected rates of return differ because of differential risk premiums across all

securities.

4. No. The value of dividend predictability would be already reflected in the

stock price.

5. No, markets can be efficient even if some investors earn returns above the market

average. Consider the Lucky Event issue: Ignoring transaction costs, about 50% of professional investors, by definition, will “beat” the market in any given year. The probability of beating it three years in a row, though small, is not insignificant.

Beating the market in the past does not predict future success as three years of

returns make up too small a sample on which to base correlation let alone causation.

6. Volatile stock prices could reflect volatile underlying economic conditions as large

amounts of information being incorporated into the price will cause variability in stock price. The efficient market hypothesis suggests that investors cannot earn

excess risk-adjusted rewards. The variability of the stock price is thus reflected in the expected returns as returns and risk are positively correlated.

7. The following effects seem to suggest predictability within equity markets and thus

disprove the efficient market hypothesis. However, consider the following:

a. Multiple studies suggest that “value” stocks (measured often by low P/E

multiples) earn higher returns over time than “growth” stocks (high P/E multiples). This could suggest a strategy for earning higher returns over time. However, another rational argument may be that traditional forms of CAPM (such as Sharpe’s model) do not fully account for all risk factors that affect a firm’s price level. A firm viewed as riskier may have a lower price and thus P/E multiple.

b. The book-to-market effect suggests that an investor can earn excess returns by investing in companies with high book value (the value of a firm’s assets minus its liabilities divided by the number of shares outstanding) to market value. A study by Fama and French1 suggests that book-to-market value reflects a risk factor that is not accounted for by traditional one variable CAPM. For example, companies

experiencing financial distress see the ratio of book to market value increase. Thus a more complex CAPM that includes book-to-market value as an explanatory variable should be used to test market anomalies.

c. Stock price momentum can be positively correlated with past performance (short to intermediate horizon) or negatively correlated (long horizon). Historical data

seem to imply statistical significance to these patterns. Explanations for this include a bandwagon effect or the behaviorists’ (see Chapter 12) explanation that there is a tendency for investors to underreact to new information, thus producing a positive serial correlation. However, statistical significance does not imply economic

significance. Several studies that included transaction costs in the momentum

models discovered that momentum traders tended to not outperform the efficient market hypothesis strategy of buy and hold.

d. The small-firm effect states that smaller firms produce better returns than larger firms. Since 1926, returns from small firms outpace large firm stock returns by

about 1% per year. Do small cap investors earn excess risk-adjusted returns?

The measure of systematic risk according to Sharpe’s CAPM is the stock’s beta (or sensitivity of returns of the stock to market returns). If the stock’s beta is the best explanation of risk, then the small-firm effect does indicate an inefficient market. Dividing the market into deciles based on their betas shows an increasing

relationship between betas and returns. Fama and French2 show that the empirical relationship between beta and stock returns is flat over a fairly long horizon (1963–1990). Breaking the market into deciles based on sizes and then examining the

relationship between beta and stock returns within each size decile exhibits this flat relationship. This implies that firm size may be a better measure of risk than beta and the size-effect should not be viewed as an indicator that markets are inefficient. Heuristically this makes sense, as smaller firms are generally viewed as risky

compared to larger firms and perceived risk and return are positively correlated. 1 Fama, Eugene and Kenneth French, “Common Risk Factors in the Returns on Stocks and Bonds,” Journal of Finance 33:1, pp. 3-56.

2 Ibid

In addition this effect seems to be endpoint and data sensitive. For example, smaller

stocks did not outperform larger stocks from the mid-1980s through the 1990s. In addition, databases contain stock returns from companies that have survived and do not include returns of those that went bankrupt. Thus small-firm data may exhibit survivorship bias.

Over the long haul, there is an expected upward drift in stock prices based on their fair expected rates of return. The fair expected return over any single day is very small (e.g., 12% per year is only about 0.03% per day), so that on any day the price is virtually equally likely to rise or fall. Over longer periods, the small expected

daily returns accumulate, and upward moves are more likely than downward ones. Remember that economies tend to grow over time and stock prices tend to follow economic growth, so it is only natural that there is an upward drift in equity prices. c. This is a predictable pattern in returns that should not occur if the weak-form

EMH is valid.

Acute market inefficiencies are temporary in nature and are more easily

exploited than chronic inefficiencies. A temporary drop in a stock price due to

a large sale would be more easily exploited than the chronic inefficiencies

mentioned in the other responses.

This is a classic filter rule that should not produce superior returns in an

efficient market.

This is the definition of an efficient market.

Though stock prices follow a random walk and intraday price changes do

appear to be a random walk, over the long run there is compensation for

bearing market risk and for the time value of money. Investing differs from a

casino in that in the long-run, an investor is compensated for these risks, while

a player at a casino faces less than fair-game odds.

In an efficient market, any predictable future prospects of a company have

already been priced into the current value of the stock. Thus, a stock share

price can still follow a random walk.

While the random nature of dart board selection seems to follow naturally

from efficient markets, the role of rational portfolio management still exists. It 8. 9. 10. a. 11. c. 12. b. 13. a. b. c.

exists to ensure a well-diversified portfolio, to assess the risk-tolerance of the

investor, and to take into account tax code issues.

14. d. In a semistrong-form efficient market, it is not possible to earn abnormally

high profits by trading on publicly available information. Information about

P/E ratios and recent price changes is publicly known. On the other hand, an

investor who has advance knowledge of management improvements could

earn abnormally high trading profits (unless the market is also strong-form

efficient).

15. Market efficiency implies investors cannot earn excess risk-adjusted profits. If the

stock price run-up occurs when only insiders know of the coming dividend increase, then it is a violation of strong-form efficiency. If the public also knows of the

increase, then this violates semistrong-form efficiency.

16. While positive beta stocks respond well to favorable new information about the

economy’s progress through the business cycle, they should not show abnormal

returns around already anticipated events. If a recovery, for example, is already

anticipated, the actual recovery is not news. The stock price should already reflect the coming recovery.

17. a. Consistent. Based on pure luck, half of all managers should beat the market

in any year.

b. Inconsistent. This would be the basis of an “easy money” rule: simply invest

with last year's best managers.

c. Consistent. In contrast to predictable returns, predictable volatility does not

convey a means to earn abnormal returns.

d. Inconsistent. The abnormal performance ought to occur in January when

earnings are announced.

e. Inconsistent. Reversals offer a means to earn easy money: just buy last

week’s losers.

18. The return on the market is 8%. Therefore, the forecast monthly return for Ford is:

0.10% + (1.1 × 8%) = 8.9%

Ford ’s actual return was 7%, so the abnormal return was –1.9%.

19. a. Based on broad market trends, the CAPM indicates that AmbChaser stock

should have increased by: 1.0% + 2.0 × (1.5% – 1.0%) = 2.0%

Its firm-specific (nonsystematic) return due to the lawsuit is $1 million per

$100 million initial equity, or 1%. Therefore, the total return should be 3%. (It

is assumed here that the outcome of the lawsuit had a zero expected value.)

If the settlement was expected to be $2 million, then the actual settlement was

a “$1 million disappointment,” and so the firm-specific return would be –1%,

for a total return of 2% – 1% = 1%. b.

20. Given market performance, predicted returns on the two stocks would be:

Apex:

Bpex: 0.2% + (1.4 × 3%) = 4.4% –0.1% + (0.6 × 3%) = 1.7%

Apex underperformed this prediction; Bpex outperformed the prediction. We

conclude that Bpex won the lawsuit.

21. a. E (r M ) = 12%, r f = 4% and β = 0.5

Therefore, the expected rate of return is:

4% + 0.5 × (12% – 4%) = 8%

If the stock is fairly priced, then E (r ) = 8%.

b. If r M falls short of your expectation by 2% (that is, 10% – 12%) then you

would expect the return for Changing Fortunes Industries to fall short of your

original expectation by: β × 2% = 1%

Therefore, you would forecast a revised expectation for Changing Fortunes of:

8% – 1% = 7%

Given a market return of 10%, you would forecast a return for Changing

Fortunes of 7%. The actual return is 10%. Therefore, the surprise due to firm-

specific factors is 10% – 7% = 3%, which we attribute to the settlement.

Because the firm is initially worth $100 million, the surprise amount of the

settlement is 3% of $100 million, or $3 million, implying that the prior

expectation for the settlement was only $2 million. c.

22. Implicit in the dollar-cost averaging strategy is the notion that stock prices

fluctuate around a “normal” level. Otherwise, there is no meaning to statements

such as: “when the price is high.” How do we know, for example, whether a price of $25 today will turn out to be viewed as high or low compared to the stock price six months from now?

23. The market responds positively to new news. If the eventual recovery is anticipated,

then the recovery is already reflected in stock prices. Only a better-than-expected recovery should affect stock prices.

24. Buy. In your view, the firm is not as bad as everyone else believes it to be.

Therefore, you view the firm as undervalued by the market. You are less pessimistic about the firm’s prospects than the beliefs built into the stock price.

25. Here we need a two-factor model relating Ford’s return to those of both the broad

market and the auto industry. If we call r I the industry return, then we would first estimate parameters α,βM ,βIND in the following regression:

r FORD =α+βM r M +βIND r IND +ε

Given these estimates we would calculate Ford’s firm-specific return as:

26. The market may have anticipated even greater earnings. Compared to prior

expectations, the announcement was a disappointment.

27. Thinly traded stocks will not have a considerable amount of market research

performed on the companies they represent. This neglected-firm effect implies a greater degree of uncertainty with respect to smaller companies. Thus positive

CAPM alphas among thinly traded stocks do not necessarily violate the efficient market hypothesis since these higher alphas are actually risk premiums, not market inefficiencies.

28. The negative abnormal returns (downward drift in CAR) just prior to stock

purchases suggest that insiders deferred their purchases until after bad news was released to the public. This is evidence of valuable inside information. The positive abnormal returns after purchase suggest insider purchases in anticipation of good news. The analysis is symmetric for insider sales.

29. a. The market risk premium moves countercyclical to the economy, peaking in

recessions. A violation of the efficient market hypothesis would imply that investors could take advantage of this predictability and earn excess risk adjusted returns. However, several studies, including Siegel,3 show that successfully timing the 3 Jeremy Siegel, Stocks for the Long Run: The Definitive Guide to Financial Market Returns and Long-Term Investment Strategies, 2002, New York: McGraw-Hill.

r FORD -[α+βM r M +βIND r IND +ε] This estimate of firm-specific news would measure the market’s assessment of the potential profitability of Ford’s new model.

b. changes have eluded professional investors thus far. Moreover a changing risk premium implies changing required rates of return for stocks rather than an inefficiency with the market. As the market risk premium increases during a recession, stocks prices tend to fall.

As the economy recovers, the market risk premium falls, and stock prices tend to rise. These changes could give investors the impression that markets overreact,

especially if the underlying changes in the market risk premium are small but

cumulative. For example, the October Crash of 1987 is commonly viewed as an

example of market overreaction. However, in the weeks running up to mid-October, several underlying changes to the market risk premium occurred (in addition to

changes in the yields on long-term Treasury Bonds). Congress threatened investors with a “merger tax” that would have truncated the booming merger industry and loosened the discipline that the threat of mergers provides to a firm’s management. In addition, the Secretary of Treasury threatened further depreciation in the value of the dollar, frightening foreign investors. These events may have increased the

market risk premium and lowered stock prices in a seeming overreaction.

CFA PROBLEMS

1. b. Semistrong form efficiency implies that market prices reflect all publicly

available information concerning past trading history as well as fundamental

aspects of the firm.

2. a. The full price adjustment should occur just as the news about the dividend

becomes publicly available.

3. d. If low P/E stocks tend to have positive abnormal returns, this would represent

an unexploited profit opportunity that would provide evidence that investors

are not using all available information to make profitable investments.

4. c. In an efficient market, no securities are consistently overpriced or underpriced.

While some securities will turn out after any investment period to have

provided positive alphas (i.e., risk-adjusted abnormal returns) and some

negative alphas, these past returns are not predictive of future returns.

5. c. A random walk implies that stock price changes are unpredictable, using past

price changes or any other data.

6.

7.

8. d. A gradual adjustment to fundamental values would allow for the use of strategies based on past price movements in order to generate abnormal profits. a. a. Some empirical evidence that supports the EMH:

(i) Professional money managers do not typically earn higher returns than

comparable risk, passive index strategies.

(ii) Event studies typically show that stocks respond immediately to the

public release of relevant news.

(iii) Most tests of technical analysis find that it is difficult to identify price

trends that can be exploited to earn superior risk-adjusted investment

returns.

Some evidence that is difficult to reconcile with the EMH concerns simple

portfolio strategies that apparently would have provided high risk-adjusted

returns in the past. Some examples of portfolios with attractive historical returns: (i) Low P/E stocks.

(ii) High book-to-market ratio stocks.

(iii) Small firms in January.

(iv) Firms with very poor stock price performance in the last few months.

Other evidence concerns post-earnings-announcement stock price drift and

intermediate-term price momentum.

An investor might choose not to index even if markets are efficient because he

or she may want to tailor a portfolio to specific tax considerations or to specific risk management issues, for example, the need to hedge (or at least not add to)

exposure to a particular source of risk (e.g., industry exposure).

The efficient market hypothesis (EMH) states that a market is efficient if

security prices immediately and fully reflect all available relevant information.

If the market fully reflects information, the knowledge of that information

would not allow an investor to profit from the information because stock

prices already incorporate the information.

i. The weak form of the EMH asserts that stock prices reflect all the information that can be derived by examining market trading data such as the history of past prices and trading volume.

A strong body of evidence supports weak-form efficiency in the major U.S.

securities markets. For example, test results suggest that technical trading rules do not produce superior returns after adjusting for transaction costs and taxes. b. c. 9. a.

ii. The semistrong form states that a firm’s stock price reflects all publicly

available information about a firm’s prospects. Examples of publicly available

information are company annual reports and investment advisory data.

Evidence strongly supports the notion of semistrong efficiency, but occasional

studies (e.g., identifying market anomalies such as the small-firm-in-January or book-to-market effects) and events (e.g. stock market crash of October 19, 1987) are inconsistent with this form of market efficiency. There is a question

concerning the extent to which these “anomalies” result from data mining.

iii. The strong form of the EMH holds that current market prices reflect all

information (whether publicly available or privately held) that can be relevant

to the valuation of the firm.

Empirical evidence suggests that strong-form efficiency does not hold. If this

form were correct, prices would fully reflect all information. Therefore even

insiders could not earn excess returns. But the evidence is that corporate

officers do have access to pertinent information long enough before public

release to enable them to profit from trading on this information.

b. i. Technical analysis involves the search for recurrent and predictable patterns in

stock prices in order to enhance returns. The EMH implies that technical analysis is without value. If past prices contain no useful information for predicting future prices, there is no point in following any technical trading rule.

ii. Fundamental analysis uses earnings and dividend prospects of the firm,

expectations of future interest rates, and risk evaluation of the firm to determine proper stock prices. The EMH predicts that most fundamental analysis is doomed to failure. According to semistrong-form efficiency, no investor can earn excess returns from trading rules based on publicly available information. Only analysts with unique insight achieve superior returns.

In summary, the EMH holds that the market appears to adjust so quickly to

information about both individual stocks and the economy as a whole that no

technique of selecting a portfolio using either technical or fundamental analysis can consistently outperform a strategy of simply buying and holding a diversified

portfolio of securities, such as those comprising the popular market indexes.

c. Portfolio managers have several roles and responsibilities even in perfectly

efficient markets. The most important responsibility is to identify the risk/return objectives for a portfolio given the investor’s constraints. In an efficient market, portfolio managers are responsible for tailoring the portfolio to meet the investor’s needs, rather than to beat the market, which requires identifying the client’s return requirements and risk tolerance. Rational portfolio management also requires

examining the investor’s constraints, including liquidity, time horizon, laws and regulations, taxes, and unique preferences and circumstances such as age and

employment.

10. a. The earnings (and dividend) growth rate of growth stocks may be consistently

overestimated by investors. Investors may extrapolate recent growth too far into the future and thereby downplay the inevitable slowdown. At any given time,

growth stocks are likely to revert to (lower) mean returns and value stocks are

likely to revert to (higher) mean returns, often over an extended future time

horizon.

In efficient markets, the current prices of stocks already reflect all known relevant information. In this situation, growth stocks and value stocks provide the same

risk-adjusted expected return. b.


相关文章

  • 9025金融市场学期末复习题
  • 哈尔滨广播电视大学开放教育本科工商管理学专业 金融市场学 期末复习题 一.名词解释(每小题5分,4小题,共20分) 1. 金融 答案: 信用与货币活动的总称 2. 信用 答案: 借贷关系 3. 金融市场主体 答案: 金融市场的基本要素之一, ...查看


  • 一级建造师06工程经济练习题(二十一)
  • 第十七章 建设工程项目投资估算与预算 一.单项选择题 1.根据国家规定,技术设计修正总概算是由( )编制. a.业主 b.设计单位 c.施工单位 d.答案b 2.下列不属于项目费用预算特征的是( ). a.控制性 b.相应性 c.计划性 d ...查看


  • 银行从业中级个人理财习题.
  • 2015年银行业中级资格考试<个人理财> 第一章练习题及答案解析 单项选择题 1.根据经验法则,如果债务负担率超过(),对生活品质可能会产生影响. A .20% B .30% C .40% D .50% 正确答案是:C 解析 根 ...查看


  • 第二章财务分析信息基础习题答案
  • 第二章财务分析信息基础作业答案 单选题 1. 在各项财务分析标准中,可比性较高的是( ) A .经验标准 B .历史标准 C .行业标准 D .预算标准 [答案]B 2. 为了评价判断企业所处的地位与水平,在分析时通常采用的标准是( ) A ...查看


  • 2016年中级经济师[中级经济基础]经典习题
  • 2016年中级经济师<中级经济基础>经典习题 一.单项选择题 1. 比较优势理论是由()提出的. A.亚当?斯密 B.赫克歇尔和俄林 C.大卫·李嘉图 D.克鲁格曼 2. ()认为,决定国际贸易的因素是两个国家产品的相对生产成本 ...查看


  • [私募股权投资基金基础知识]练习题7
  • 62股权投资基金的募集,是指()向投资者募集资金用于设立股权投资基 金的行为. A.股权投资基金管理人或者受其委托的募集服务机构 B.股权投资基金管理人 C.受其委托的募集服务机构 D.以上都对 参考答案:A 股权投资基金的募集,是指股权 ...查看


  • 2014年国家公务员考试行测题库:经济常识习题及答案
  • 2014年国家公务员考试行测题库:经济常识习题及答案 国家公务员考试行测题库: 1.农业在国民经济中的基础地位主要表现在( ) A.为人们提供基本生活资料 B.为轻工业提供重要原料 C.为工业发展提供广阔市场 D.为经济建设提供资金积累 2 ...查看


  • 交易性金融资产练习题1答案
  • 第一章(一) 交易性金融资产练习题答案 一.单项选择题 1.某股份有限公司于2007年3月30日购入某上市公司股票50万股,划分为交易性金融资产.该股票在购买日的公允价值为600万元.购买该股票另支付的手续费为10万元,5月22日收到该上市 ...查看


  • SYB创业培训教材练习题参考答案
  • 说明:本书的练习题没有标准案,这里准备的答案仅供读者参考.如果读者在今后工作中,对这个答案有新的发展或者作出批评和修改,并不断完善,那么这个答案就达到目的了. 练习一 李明的鸡场 一.李明的企业为什么会倒闭? 直接原因是现金流量出现负值,无 ...查看


  • 2016事业单位行政能力测试练习题
  • 2016事业单位行政能力测试练习题 根据以下资料,回答1-5题. 20世纪90年代,我国人口出生率和自然增长率由1990年的千分之21.06和千分之14.39降至1998年的千分之16.03和千分之9.53,人口自然增长率已经首次低于千分之 ...查看


热门内容